Export cartels - a century of fumble attitudes?

AuthorCristina Gonta
PositionAssistant Lawyer at the European Court of Human Rights
Pages1-32
1
EXPORT CARTELS – A CENTURY OF FUMBLE ATTITUDES?
Cristina Gonta
1)
Republic of Moldova
Assistant Lawyer at the European Court of Human Rights
Abstract
The present article analyzes, from a historical perspective, the debate
concerning the export cartel debate from its birth in 1918 until today. There can
be identified four different periods of the debate that revolve around the
enactment of the Webb-Pomerene Act, the creation of the Bretton Woods
institutions, the creation of the World Trade Organization and the July package
decision of 1 July 2004. The article highlights the actors and the ideas that
shaped the debate and the results that were obtained. While it is clear that the
fairest solution to the issue of export cartels would be the prohibition of this
practice, what is not clear is the path that would lead to the ban and the
institutional framework that would support it afterwards. This paper thus
proposes an approach for identifying the most affordable solution. It argues
however that, before launching an institutionalized solution on export cartels,
more in depths analysis is needed
2)
.
Keywords: export cartels; World Trade Organization; competition law; cartels
INTRODUCTION
1. In a global world some issues become, inevitably, more visible. One such
issue is the practice of providing exemptions from national competition legislation
to firms that cooperate in their export activities, known also as the export cartel
exemption.
2. The export cartels are “mysterious” cartels. While international cartels
received and continue receiving attention both from the national authorities and
from the International Organizations (IGOs), export cartels remain almost
unobserved. This paper presents the evolution of the export cartels debate that
began in 1918 with the enactment in the US of the Webb-Pomerene Act, the main
actors and ideas that shaped the debate, and the achieved results. The paper also
1)
Cristina Gonta (Republic of Moldova) is a n Assistant Lawyer at the European Court of
Human Rights and a PhD student at the Univer sity of Bern. This paper represents the personal
opinions of the author and does not engage in any way the responbilit y of the author’s employer.
Article published in the journal “Law” nr. 11/2010, pp. 326–355.
2)
The present paper is the result of a research carried out during a LLM pr ogram under the
supervision of Thomas Cottier, Professor at the University of Bern.
2
attempts to emit some general conclusions concerning the evolution of trade
relations and trade law thinking that accompanied the export cartels debate.
The paper is divided into four parts which present the waves of academic
thinking on export cartels. The first part depicts the first years of the 20
th
century.
The second part highlights the evolution of the export cartel debate after the
World War II (WWII). The third part follows the development of the export cartel
debate after the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO). The last part
focuses on the very recent works on export cartels that were published after the
failure of the trade and competition debate within the WTO. A special emphasis
will be placed in the last part of the present dissertation on the feasible solutions
for the export cartel issue.
I. THE WEB-POMERENE MOMENTUM
The legal writing on trade and competition is not a recent invention. The
survey of the early literature on export cartels surprises with the amount, the
quality and the depth of the legal thinking at the beginning of the 20
th
century.
In relation to the enactment of the Webb-Pomerene Act, it is interesting to
highlight, from the point of view of the modern lawyer, the reasons for the
adoption of such legislation, the advantages and disadvantages of enacting such
legislation and some of the specific questions asked by the academics who first
considered this issue.
The Webb-Pomerene Act (WPA) was adopted in 1918. The Act was designed
to promote the American export trade by granting relief from the Sherman Act
provisions to the so-called export associations.
Since a proper balance must have been struck between a provision that would
have de facto repealed the Sherman Act and a provision that would have given the
American exporters what they required, the reasons for enacting such legislation
were carefully considered.
One could identify four main reasons that lead to the adoption of the Webb-
Pomerene Act.
a) An eye for an eye, a cartel for a cartel
Export associations were considered a legal answer to a late business start. In
order to compete with the already established and very powerful German
3)
,
British, Dutch or Japanese “combinations”, the small American business needed
to be empowered with a necessary business wisdom, the wisdom of association
4)
.
Since all the leading trade nations of those times allowed associations for the
3)
Steven B. Webb, ‘Tariffs, Cartels, Technology and Growth in the Germa n Steel Industry,
1879 to 1914’ (1980) 40 The Journal Of Economic History 2, 309 -330.
4)
Eliot Jones, ‘The Webb-Pomerene Act’ (1920) 28 The Journal Of Political Economy 9, 754.
3
promotion of exports, the American exporters saw the Sherman Act, which did
not provide for such an exemption, as a betrayal. As Kirsh observed, “a more
tolerant attitude than that evidenced by the American anti-trust policy is
manifested by all of the governments of foreign nations. There are at present in no
European country restrictive legal provisions which embody the regulations and
contain the drastic penalties of the American anti-trust laws”
5)
.
The export association legislation was, on the other hand, a general policy
choice. Canadian trade officials and the British Board of Trade – that historically
and culturally praised individualism and condemned monopolist tendencies –
strongly supported export association legislation
6)
.
Finally, the export associations were needed to respond to the European
combinations of buyers that had the effect of lowering the price of the exported
American goods
7)
.
In the light of these arguments it appears that the Webb-Pomerene Act was, at
the time of its adoption, a necessary law.
b) Solving a bigger puzzle
The Webb-Pomerene Act represented only one piece of a larger policy which
endeavored to promote U.S. foreign trade. The inadequate banking and credit
facilities abroad, the discrimination against the American goods by foreign
steamship lines, the small amount of American investment in the securities of
foreign companies and the comparative inexperience
8)
of American business
society needed to be compensated by strong incentives to export and to invest.
One such incentive was granted by the WPA aimed to lower the export costs, to
secure better credit information and thus better financing of the business and to
allow an exchange of know-how between the members of the association.
The Shipping Board Act, the Edge Act, the Merchant Marine Act were part of
the same logic, providing exemptions from the anti-trust laws and making
available new financial means for foreign trade promotion
9)
.
c) Stop competing with each other!
One could also identify an unconventional reason for the adoption of the
WPA: the intention to make the American exporters stop competing with each
other in the foreign markets. This idea is highlighted by Eliot who noted that the
elimination of competition between the American firms will lead to better prices
5)
Benj amin S. Kirsh, ‘For eign Trade Functions of Trade Associations: The Legal Aspects’
(1928) 76 University Of Pennsilvania Law Review 8, 894.
6)
William Notz, ‘Cartels During the War’ (1919) 27 The Journal Of Po litical Economy 1, 6-7
7)
Jones (1920), 757.
8)
Ibid., 757.
9)
Kirsh (1928), 913.
4
for the products sold abroad
10)
. In the same sense, another author wrote “that it is
not the economies of combination that attract Webb-Pomerene association
activities. Rather it is the opportunity to lessen competitive rivalry, ostensibly in
foreign markets”
11)
. In this way what was supposed to act as an incentive to export
became in fact an incentive to cartelize.
The biggest amount of information available about export associations relates
to the advantages and disadvantages that such legislation exhibits. Two
observations should be made at this point. First, it appears that the only absolute
supporter of the export association legislation was the Federal Trade Commission.
Except of the FTC, few authors voiced unconditional support for the WPA.
Second, the number of critics surpassed from the beginning the number of the
WPA supporters.
In a report issued in 1927, the Federal Trade Commission enumerated the
advantages of the export trade associations: (1) reduction of the selling and
transport costs; (2) standardization of business practices; (3) improvement of
product quality; (4) elimination of the cut-throat competition in the foreign
markets; (5) economy in operation; (6) better distribution systems; (7) prorating of
business data collection
12)
.
One of the few supporters of the Webb statute concluded in 1929 that the
WPA “has provided thus far a serviceable piece of legislation and within
reasonable bounds accomplished what its name proclaims: An Act to Promote
Export Trade”
13)
.
On the side of academics who voiced rather skeptical views, two main types
of criticism can be identified in relation to the implementation of the WPA: (a)
egotistic criticism and (b) altruistic criticism.
a. Egotistic criticisms
“The chief objection to the export associations authorized by the Webb Act is
that they may be used as a means of restricting competition in the domestic
market”
14)
. As Fournier explains, the idea that domestic market and foreign
markets are separate is “entirely erroneous” since “the two markets cannot be kept
distinct and separate without restraint of competition in both markets”
15)
.
Taken into account the intensive international cartel activity before the WWI,
many authors expressed the view that the removal of the Sherman Act restrictions
10)
Jones (1920), 757.
11)
Leslie T. Fournier, ‘The Purpose and Results of the Webb -Pomerene Law’ ( 1932) 22 The
American Economic Review 1, 20.
12)
Anual Report Of Federal Trade Commission for year ending June, 1927 , paragraph 23.
13)
William Notz, ‘Ten Years’ Operation o f the Webb Law’ (1929) 19 The American
Economic Review 1, 19.
14)
Jones (1920), 765.
15)
Fournier (1932), 26.
5
as regards the export trade associations will lead to the proliferation of
international cartels
16)
.
Another fear expressed by the academia was that the “a cartel for a cartel”
approach might be just the beginning of a trade war. The Webb statute may create
a reaction on the side of the foreign competitors that could seek to expand the
already existing cartels in order to react to the newly empowered American
business
17)
.
Fournier pointed out that the Webb-Pomerene Act was very likely to create
“serious administrative difficulties”, by placing on the Department of Justice a
heavier burden of proof as to the domestic restraint on trade.
b. Altruistic criticisms
One of the most astonishing and prophetical criticism expressed in relation to
the WPA at the beginning of the last century was the so-called “world consumers
issue”
18)
. Fournier noted that the Webb bill and its future interpretations represent
a “vehicle for the oppression of foreign people”, proposing already in the 1920s
what today would be classified under the name of accountability.
Jones noted that, except of a trade war, “the pursuit of trade by large groups
will tend to upset once more the peace of the world”
19)
. In the same way Notz,
while highlighting the “dangerous effects of commercial friction upon the political
relations among nations”, suggests that the only healthy way in which trade could
be pursued in the future is to “give to commerce the humane imprint which shall
always constitute the emblem of genuine civilization and enlightenment”
20)
.
In sum, the WPA was the first concrete attempt to establish a policy on export
associations. The Act was part of the US competition policy, and a step ahead
towards the crystallization of an American trade policy.
The WPA was an expression of a political wisdom. No special legal necessity
or economic reasoning seemed to require this amendment to the Sherman Act.
The fact that Woodrow Wilson himself intervened two times to ask the Congress
to speed up the process of adoption of an export association bill points out to the
weight that the political, rather than the legal or economic, interests played in the
adoption of this law.
Furthermore, it appears that the initial commentators of the WPA were more
concerned with its political impact rather than with its legal impact. Thus the
debate whether cartels ensure peace by guaranteeing that competitors will not
intervene in each others’ markets or, on contrary, may lead to a war by developing
16)
William Notz, ‘International Private Agreements in the Fo rm of Cartels, Syndicates, and
Other Combinations’ (1920) 28 The Journal Of Political Economy 8, 667-671.
17)
Jones (1920), 766.
18)
Fournier (1932), 19.
19)
Jones (1920), 766.
20)
Notz (1919), 45.
6
an ill-feeling among nations prevailed in the American academia. In fact, the
export association legislation was seen against the peace time-war time
background. The fact that the Treaty of Versailles which was a peace-making
treaty – obliged Germany “to protect the trade of the Allies against unfair
competition” is symptomatic of the tendency in the policy making process of that
time to balance out the benefits from trade with the possible damages to the world
peace. This leads inevitably to the idea that the export association legislation was
perceived as political necessity in the first instance, the economic and legal
reasoning on efficiencies or enforcement was absent or only at the periphery of
the academic interest.
Also, one could assume that the WPA was an important component of the
American endeavor to quit its isolationist instincts. The increase of trade officials,
the amendment of banking laws and the campaigns for “building up among the
people of the United States an appreciation of the significance of international
trade”
21)
lead to the conclusion that trade was perceived as a great opportunity for
the American business to meet the outside world. The Webb law was only one of
the incentives to do so and, as such, part of a systemic change.
One should also mention the prophetic talent of the academic debate revolving
around the Webb bill. The references to the “world consumers”, the expressed need
for an international mechanism to prevent unfair competition, and the enforcement
problems are questions that challenge the minds and the personal philosophy of
modern lawyers and economists, just as they did almost one century ago.
Lastly, one could affirm that the Webb Act was a legal text issued from a
realistic reasoning, but which had an idealistic bias. On the one hand, the purpose
of the act was clearly to empower the small American businesses to compete with
foreign players. On the other hand, the wording “export association” (instead of
“export cartel”) tends to put the same behaviour – cartelization for the purpose of
dividing markets, imposing prices or building barriers to entry – in a more
favorable light, thus leading to the conclusion that the initiators of the Act
believed, out of an idealistic inrush, that export associations will represent a sort
of higher good.
II. THE BRETTON WOODS MOMENTUM
1. (Big) Politics that Shaped (Small) Policies
The WWII left behind a politically, economically and legally “depressed”
world. That is why any attempt to explain policy choices of that era should be
followed by this vision of a politically, economically and legally “depressed” world.
21)
Chauncey D. Snow, ‘American Foreign Trade Problems’ (1924) 14 The American Economic
Review 1, 7.
7
While the main concern after the WWI was to restore peace, the main concern
after the WWII was to maintain peace. Also, while peace after the WWI meant
mainly security of borders, peace after WWII meant well-being of everyone. The
commercial policy features of the treaties ending the WWI were minimal and the
attempts to develop trade relationships after the WWI were loose
22)
. This was not
the case after the WWII, when trade was affirmed not only as one of the pillars of
international relations, but also as guardian of the world peace. That is why the
post-war vision as achieved at Bretton Woods in 1944 entailed that the future
economic structure shall include the International Monetary Fund, the
International Bank for Development and Reconstruction and the International
Trade Organization (ITO). Even if the ITO never came into being, the fact that a
trade organization was placed on the Bretton Woods agenda proves that trade was
considered as one of the future pieces in the international relations game. What is
more, the agreement to cut tariffs and make other concessions represented “a
dramatic break from earlier ‘mercantilist’ approach to trade and was intended to
inaugurate a new era of open commerce”
23)
.
One might say that the founders of the Bretton Woods system adopted a
“maximal” approach to trade. As the Havana Charter suggests, trade relations
were supposed to bring about not only the reduction of tariffs (which would
account for the “minimal” approach to trade), but more broadly employment, non-
discrimination and higher volume of income. In this sense, the Havana Charter
contained provisions not only concerning tariffs and quantitative restrictions
which represent the core of any trade policy – but also provisions on subsidies,
commodity agreements, employment and restrictive business practices.
In the context of the “maximal” approach to trade, the debate on the
restrictive business practices was an important one, both for policy-makers and for
scholars. In this sense, the Havana Charter stipulated that:
Each Member shall take appropriate measures and shall co-operate with the
Organization to prevent, on the part of private or public commercial enterprises,
business practices affecting international trade which restrain competition, limit
access to markets, or foster monopolistic control, whenever such practices have
harmful effects on the expansion of production or trade
24)
.
The practices targeted by the Havana Charter included inter alia:
22)
Charles Kindleberg, ‘Commercial P olicy between the Wars’ in Peter Mathias and Sidney
Pollard (eds) The Cambridge Ec onomic History of Europe (1989) Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 161- 196; Charles H. Feinstein, Peter Temin and Gianni Tonniolo, ‘The Legacy
of the First War’ in The European Economy between the Wars (1997 ) Oxford: OUP, 18-37.
23)
Tony Judt, Postwar: A History of Europe since 1945 (2005) New York: Penguin Books, 107.
24)
Havana Charter for an International Trade Organization, 24 March, 1948, U. N Doc./E
C.2/78, reprinted in Dep’t St., Pub. No. 3206, Commercial P olicy Series 114, 86-87 (1948)
(hereinafter ‘Havana Charter’), Article 46.
8
(a) fixing prices, terms or conditions to be observed in dealing with others in
the purchase, sale or lease of any product;
(b) excluding enterprises from, or allocating or dividing, any territorial market
or field of business activity, or allocating customers, or fixing sales quotas or
purchase quotas;
(c) discriminating against particular enterprises;
(d) limiting production or fixing production quotas.
The Havana Charter provided for a consultation procedure, an investigation
procedure and special procedures with respect to services for the remedial of a
situation that potentially affects international trade by restricting competition,
limiting access to markets and fostering monopolistic control. If consultations
could not resolve the problem, than all the Members sitting in the Conference had
the opportunity to refer the issue to the UN executive board for further review.
The International Court of Justice could review the decisions taken by the
Conference
25)
.
As a later account pointed out, implicit in the Havana Charter was “the idea
that government actions in the domestic market can affect the international
movement of goods, capital, and services. The idea driving the negotiations was
that governments should obligate themselves to not only providing MFN and
national treatment to the goods and nationals of other Member States, but to
constructing a domestic economy without access barriers (e.g., through the
obligations on restrictive business practices to investment protection)”
26)
.
2. The Academic Debate
The Havana Charter provisions on restrictive business practices were
preceded by a passionate academic debate. Two main ideas were developed by the
scholarly literature during the Bretton Woods era: first, that cartel activity is
dangerous and, second, that action against combines is necessary for the
attainment of a lasting peace.
After an inter bellum period characterized both by the fact that cartelization
was perceived as a necessary part of the surviving philosophy during the
belligerence and by the fact that cartelization substituted government action in
many instances, the academic society seemed to arrive at the conclusion that
cartels represent a dangerous business practice. As Taylor puts it, “after the World
War II, a paradigm shift in international thought occurred in which the adverse
political consequences of industrial cartelization were clearly recognized, as were
the adverse welfare effects of excessive concentration of economic power”
27)
.
25)
Havana Charter, Chapter VIII, ‘Settlement of Differences’.
26)
Peter S. Watson, Joseph E. Flynn and Chad C. Conwell, Completing the World Tradeing
System:Proposals for a Millennium Round (1999) The Hague: Kluwer Law International, 349.
27)
Taylor (2006), 149.
9
It was recognized that cartels restrict international trade
28)
and mitigate the
effects of reducing the tariff walls
29)
. They reduce competition, diminish the
incentives to innovate, limit the possibilities for the buyers to protect themselves
against low quality and limit new industrial capacity
30)
. Furthermore, authors that
followed the development of international cartels in the interwar period argued that
a link might be established between, on the one side, the cartel activity and, on the
other side, the left-wing politics and the antidemocratic movements like Fascism,
Hispanidad and Kokutai. In addition, in the international trade game, cartel activity
subdues not only individuals and companies, but also industries and governments.
One author concluded that “history has proven the cartel justifiers grossly in
error. Actually the cartel system fostered an economic Balkanization of the world.
It set up artificial economic states, commodity by commodity, each with its own
government, laws, division and trade barriers, imposed and superimposed over
one another with increasing complexity”
31)
.
During this period, it was acknowledged for the first time at the international
level that action was needed to prevent and counteract the effects that cartels
might have on trade
32)
. Action by both international and national policy-makers
was considered to be necessary
33)
. Even more, it was emphasized that only the
combined national and international efforts could lead to a successful geometry
against combines
34)
and that every policy concerning cartels should be based on
well-established principles and should be accompanied by attuned economic and
legal reasoning.
Despite the impressive number of works written on cartels dating from that
period, the export cartel issue seemed to be of no interest for the academia. This
contradiction can be explained, in part, by the broad formulation of Article 46 of
the Havana Charter and, in part, by the lack of political will to pursue such
practices. On the one hand, the Charter provision on restrictive business practices
could have been easily interpreted to prohibit – in case there was such a need -
practices like export cartels. On the other hand, the post-WWII pax Americana
opened promising markets for the US exporters. And while the US was the only
28)
F. E. Koch, ‘Cartels as Instruments of Internat ional Economic Organization. Public and
Private Legal Aspects of International Cartels’ (1945) 8 The Mode rn Law Review 3, 131.
29)
Theodore J. Kreps, ‘Cartels, a P hase of Business Haute Politique’ (1945) 35 The American
Economic Review 2, 309.
30)
Corwin D. Edwards, ‘International Cartels as Obstacle s to International Trade’ (1944) 34
The American Economic Review 1, 331-333.
31)
Quoted by Robert Liefman, International Cartels, Combines, and Trusts (1927) London:
Routledge and Sons, 100.
32)
Corwin D. Edwards (1944), 337.
33)
Klaus E Knorr, ‘The Problem of International Cartels and I ntergovernmental Commod ity
Agreements’ (1946) 55 The Yale Law Journal 5, 1105.
34)
Heinrich Kronstein, Gertrude Leighton, ‘Cartel Control: A record of Failure’ (1946) 55
The Yale Law Journal 2, 297.
10
exporter capable of satisfying the post-WWII needs, it appeared unreasonable for
the US policy-makers to deprive the American exporters of an important tool to
penetrate markets. In this context it is important to recall that the Havana Charter
was sabotaged by the US for various reasons
35)
: “The US State Department
viewed the Havana Charter as a threat to stricter US competition laws, while the
US Congress viewed it as an unwarranted threat to US economic hegemony and
domestic political sovereignty in the post-war era”
36)
.
A researcher following the evolution of the export cartels literature after the
WWII will be surprised by a contradiction. On the one hand, the provisions of the
Havana Charter prove the maturity of values of over fifty nations that by 1950
have ratified it. For that time the linking of trade, employment and social policy
constituted “a revolution in state policy making”
37)
. Also, “the consensus
embodied in the Havana Charter was path breaking for the nations of the world
because it created the template for all other similar broad initiatives”
38)
. On the
other hand however, the failure of the ITO project stands for the “immaturity” of
the international community to enforce these values.
This contradiction characterizes in fact the approach to trade during the whole
post-WWII period. As Moon notes, “although a liberal trading order was the
paramount objective of Bretton Woods, mercantilist concerns never disappeared,
and as a result, the tensions and discontinuities embodied in these two visions
became imbedded in the system itself”
39)
. On the one hand, the GATT and the trade
liberalization rounds brought further and further the free trade ideal and gave a new
meaning to trade relations in general. On the other hand, the League of Nations
wounds
40)
, the national egoisms and incapacities combined with the newly founded
American hegemony and the endeavor to protect the American industry interests
41)
brought about a paralytic international trade system that was not ready to respond to
some very important issues. One such issue was that of export cartels which was
likely to lead to the exploitation of the world consumers and which enforced “a
theoretical dichotomy in the philosophy of business operations”
42)
.
35)
G. Diebold, The End of the ITO: Essays in International Financ e No. 16 (1952) Princeton:
Princeton University, para. 2.5.
36)
Taylor (2006), 153.
37)
Daniel Drache, ‘The Short but Si gnificant Life of the International Trade Organization:
Lessons for Our Time’ (2000) CSGR Working Paper No. 62/00, 2 8.
38)
Ibidem, 23.
39)
Bruce E. Moon, Dilemmas of International Trade (2000) Oxford: W estwood Press, 91.
40)
Alfred E. Eckes Jr., ‘U.S. Trade Histor y’ in William A. Lovett, Alfred E. Eckes Jr. and
Richard L. Brinkman (eds), U.S . Trade Policy: History, Theory and the WTO (1999) New York:
M. E. Sharpe, 75.
41)
Andreas Dür, ‘Foreign Discrimination, Protection for Exporters, and U.S. Trade
Liberalization’ (2007) International Studies Quaterly 51, 457-480.
42)
Sidney A. Diamond, ‘The Webb -Pomerene Act and Export Trade Associations’ (1944) 44
Columbia Law Review 6, 832.
11
III. THE TRADE AND COMPETITION MOMENTUM
The debate on export cartels had its peak hour after the creation of the WTO
within the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition
Policy (WGTCP) and raised not only issues regarding the effects of the anti-
competitive behaviour on trade, but also issues regarding the developing countries
and the role of the WTO as such.
The issue of export cartels was heavily debated within the WGTCP. The
positions expressed reflect in fact the divide between the export cartels-friendly
countries and the export cartels-unfriendly countries. The US is the primary
example of an export cartel-friendly country. From all the communications
submitted by the US to the WGTCP between 1996-2004 only one mentioned the
issue of export cartels and this occurred at a rather late stage of negotiations. On
that occasion, the US pointed out that the issue of export cartels requires “further
and more focused discussion among WTO Members”
43)
. The European
Community (EC), on the other hand, condemned the export cartels since its first
communication to the WGTCP
44)
and constantly touched upon this issue during
the following years. One unexpected export cartels-unfriendly country was Japan.
Japan enacted legislation that exempted export cartels from the application of anti-
trust rules and made heavy use of this exemption to promote its industries.
However, during the life of the WGTCP, Japan expressed constant calls for an
international prohibition of export cartels
45)
.
Because of the fact that the Member States of the WTO expressed their
positions on export cartels in the context of the wider interface between trade and
competition, interesting linkages and conclusion were made. Two main types of
concerns were raised by the Member States in relation to the subject-matter of this
paper. First, Governments addressed substantive legal questions in relation to
export cartels. Second, important procedural concerns were expressed.
1. The WGTCP Substantive Challenge
During the existence of the WGTCP the WTO member States addressed the
following questions. First, the role of the WTO in dealing with trade and competition
interface was considered
46)
. Then, the ideological difference between trade policy and
43)
Communication from the United States, Working Grou p on the Interaction between Trade
and Competition Policy, WTO, WT/WGTCP/W/203 (data), paragrap h 7-8.
44)
Communication from the European Community and its Member States, W T/WGTCP/W/1.
45)
In this se nse, see the following communications form Japan: WT/WGTCP/W/52,
WT/WGTCP/W/119, WT/WGTCP/W/134, WT/WGTCP/W/135, WT/WGTCP/W/156 and
WT/WGTCP/W/177.
46)
Repor t (2000) of the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition
Policy to the General Council, WT/WGTCP/4, p aragraph 82-83; Report (2001) of the Working
12
competition policy was tackled. In this sense, it was mentioned that the export cartel
exemption “gave excessive weight to the interests of national consumers and
producers, to the neglect of the interests of consumers in other countries”
47)
.
Third, the impact of the export cartels was discussed. The question whether
export cartels affect or not international trade was a crucial one. If this business
practice had an adverse effect on trade, then the call for multilateral action was
justified. If, on contrary, this type of collusion did not restrict international trade,
then the rationale for a multilateral agreement was missing.
In the WGTCP the view was expressed that export cartels restrict competition
in foreign markets
48)
. Export cartels were also used “as a strategic trade policy to
extract rents from foreign countries”
49)
. Other countries held the view that export
cartels “had pro-competitive effects in that they added additional players to the
relevant markets and might bring innovation or lower prices. Moreover, they were
not secret and therefore did not bear the hallmarks of what was traditionally
considered to be a hardcore cartel”
50)
. Responding to this last point, the
clarification was offered that “in fact, most export cartels involved multinational
companies, not small and medium-sized enterprises of the sort that might need to
bind together for efficiency purposes”
51)
.
The issue of developing countries was raised constantly in the framework of
the export cartels debate. It was stressed that “the victims of export cartels” often
included developing countries which were importing machinery or consumer
products. Furthermore, it was suggested “that the extent of such cartels and their
deleterious effects on international trade and development might well be greater
than was widely known, since most countries did not insist on registration of such
cartels; they simply turned a blind eye to them”
52)
. In addition, the point was made
that “developing countries should be allowed to exempt national and international
export cartels, since most developing countries' exporters or importers were
mainly small scale and might need to bind together to counter the bargaining
power of larger buyers or sellers from industrialized countries”
53)
.
Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition Po licy to the Ge neral Council,
WT/WGTCP/5, paragraph 101.
47)
WTO (1998), Report of the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and
Competition Policy to the General Council, WT/WGTCP/2, para graph 26.
48)
Repor t (1999) of the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition
Policy to the General Council, WT/WGTCP/3, paragraph 71.
49)
Repor t (2002) of the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition
Policy to the General Council, WT/WGTCP/6, paragraph 27.
50)
Repor t (2003) of the Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition
Policy to the General Council, WT/WGTCP/7, paragraph 51.
51)
Ibidem, paragraph 52.
52)
Report (1998), paragraph 89.
53)
Report (2002), paragraph 35.
13
2. The WGTCP Procedural Challenge
Besides the substantive legal questions a few procedural concerns were
addressed during the work of the WGTCP in relation to export cartels.
First, it was recognized that in order to tackle such anti-competitive practices
in an effective manner, “there was a need for both effective national competition
policies and enhanced international cooperation at the bilateral, regional and
multilateral levels”
54)
.
Second, it was pointed out that in dealing with export cartels and other anti-
competitive practices at the national level, measures to promote the progressive
development of institutional capacities, the existence of effective and transparent
enforcement powers and the appropriate protection of confidential information
were needed
55)
.
Third, it was emphasized that the positive comity was unlikely to be an
appropriate tool to deal with export cartels because the requested country might be
reluctant to enforce its competition law at the expense of its own domestic
industry and primarily for the benefit of the complaining country
56)
.
Fourth, the jurisdictional emasculation in dealing with export cartels was
highlighted. On the one hand, the home authorities cannot punish the export
cartels because they have no or little effect on the domestic market. On the other
hand, the countries on whose markets the export cartels are active cannot pursue
them because they lack the necessary anti-trust tools and information. This led to
the conclusion that international cooperation was the appropriate means to deal
with these arrangements “since there were jurisdictional limits to the solution of
the problem solely through the application of competition legislation in the
exporting country”
57)
.
Lastly, it was suggested that the international cooperation in the field of
export cartels should be based on the principle of “no less favourable treatment in
terms of competition rights for citizens or firms of foreign countries than that
accorded to firms or nationals of the host country”
58)
.
3. The Academic Dispute
In parallel with the political debate in the WTO, an academic debate took
place in the scholarly circles. The following features can be said to characterize
the academic debate on export cartels from the 1990s on.
54)
Report (2001), paragraph 62.
55)
Report (1999), paragraph 26.
56)
Ibidem, paragraph 42.
57)
Report (2003), paragraph 50.
58)
Report (1999), paragraph 27.
14
a. Economic analysis of export cartels
Starting with the 1990s, the analysis of export cartels was permeated with
economic thinking. The main question raised was whether export cartels are
efficiency-enhancing or monopoly-promoting. Using different economics tools,
researchers attempted to predict in which sectors export cartels were more likely
to form. As a result, an anatomy of the Webb-Pomerene cartel was developed.
First, it was concluded that Webb-Pomerene cartels were more likely to ship
non-durable, capital-intensive, standardized products, to form in industries with
low seller concentration, and to form in growing export markets where the United
States had large market share
59)
.
Second, when describing the functions pursued by the Webb cartels, Dick
states that 45% of the Webb associations had as their primary function the setting
of common prices and/or the allocation of markets. The remaining 55% of Webb
cartels were used as an instrument to capture economies of scale
60)
.
Third, it was noted that export cartels were relatively short-lived, did not
reorganize after dissolution and did not become more stable due to the age or
experience
61)
.
b. Maybe export cartels are not so bad in the end?
One of the implications of the above-outlined economic analysis was the
conclusion that export associations do not always restrict trade and competition in
the foreign and in the domestic markets.
As regards the foreign markets, empirical research by Andrew Dick led to the
conclusion that the primary goal of the Webb-Pomerene associations was to assist
exports and that only a small part of the existing Webb-Pomerene associations can
in fact exercise overseas market power. In addition, Dick’s study on sixteen
commodities showed that foreign consumers benefited from the existence of
export cartels in six instances and were adversely affected in only three instances.
Also, the WPA benefited the US producers in nine industries by lowering costs or
enabling successful exercise of foreign market power
62)
.
In the same vein, Waller expressed the view that “the history of the Webb-
Pomerene Act suggests that few export associations will have sufficient global
market power to exploit foreign markets”
63)
.
59)
Andrew R. Dick, ‘Identifying Contracts, Co mbinations and Conspiracies in Restraint of
Trade’(1996) 17 Managerial And Decision Economics 2, 213.
60)
Ibidem.
61)
Andr ew R. Dick, ‘When Are Cartels Stable Contracts?’ (1996) 39 Journal Of Law And
Economics 1, 255-257.
62)
Andrew R. Dick, ‘Are Export Cartels Efficiency-Enhancing or Monopoly-Promoting?
Evidence from the Webb-Pomerene Experience’ (1992) 15 Research In Law And Economics, 89-127.
63)
Spencer Weber Waller, ‘The Failure of the Export Trading Company Program’ (1992) 17
North Carolina Journal Of International Law And Commercial Regulatio n, 251-252.
15
A different approach to this issue was taken by Evenett, Levenstein and
Suslow. In their study these authors suggest that the global competition race might
sometimes dictate a choice between two evils. The collusive behaviour might
appear as the least dangerous option. Thus, a firm seeking to build the necessary
scale which would ensure a ticket for the global competition race can choose
between the creation of an export cartel and a merger or a joint venture. In this
case the first option seems to have the least anticompetitive effects
64)
.
As regards the domestic market, it was concluded that it will sense the
anticompetitive effect due to the formation of an export cartel only in the case of a
monopoly-promoting cartel. According to this line of argumentation the
anticompetitive spill-over will not reach the domestic market in case of an
efficiency-enhancing export cartel
65)
.
Strongly contrasting conclusions were reached by other scholars. A study
conducted by Larson concluded that the pursuit of monopoly profits abroad
guided the creation and existence of export cartels
66)
. In addition, export cartels
represent a beggar-your-neighbour policy because the “home country where such
cartel originates always gains, and the foreign country loses”
67)
. As such, the
restrictions on international trade created by export cartels not only reduce global
supply and welfare, but also hurt the interests of trading partners
68)
.
In relation to the work of the WGTCP Marsden noted that Members “raised
issues about almost every form of business arrangement, besides the policy
considered most directly relevant to their mandate: competition policy itself”
69)
.
Still, Marsden emphasized that the topic of export cartels should be addressed in
the framework of the WTO. An agreement on this issue would enhance the anti-
cartel co-operation and enforcement operations. Furthermore, export cartels
represent a truly development-related agenda concern and would find its place in
Doha easily
70)
.
Another important input was made by Victor. He argued that due to the fact
that since 1976 the Webb-Pomerene associations accounted for only 1.5 percent
of the US exports, the US export cartel statutes were not able to accomplish their
goals. Instead the Webb statute only facilitated some anticompetitive conduct,
64)
Simon J. Evenett, Margaret C. Levenstein and Valerie Y. Suslow, ‘International Cartel
Enforcement: Lessons fro m the 1990s’ (2002) World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No.
2680, 1233, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=265741 (last visited on 17 May 2009).
65)
Christia n Sc hultz, ‘Export Cartels and Domestic Markets’ (2002) 2 Journal Of Industry,
Competition And Trade 3, 223-246.
66)
David A. Larson, ‘An Eco nomic Analysis of the Webb-Pomerene Act’ (197 0) 13 Journal
Of Law And Economics, 461-500.
67)
Sadao Nagaoka, ‘International Trade Aspects of Competition Policy’ (1998) NBER Working
Paper 6720, 3 available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w6720.pdf (last visited on 17 May 2009).
68)
Ibidem, 2.
69)
Philip Marsden, A Competition Policy for the WTO (2003) Cameron May, London, 59.
70)
Ibidem, 87.
16
both abroad and in the US market. For this, “the Webb Act has proven to be a
dismal failure”
71)
. Still, in formulating a recommendation, Victor argued that
protection should be withdrawn only from the monopoly-promoting export
cartels. Protection for efficiency-enhancing collusion should remain in place
72)
.
c. Export cartels and other fiends
One important feature of the scholarly literature that accompanied the 1990s
debate on export cartels was the endeavour to link the issue of export cartels to
other subject-matters.
In the context of the more classical linkage between competition law and
intellectual property law a novel conclusion was drawn as to the relation between
intellectual property law and export cartels. In this sense, Cottier and Meitinger
argue that “the lawful existence of export cartels in most jurisdictions is likely to
reinforce the doctrine of national exhaustion and thus of market segregation
abroad”
73)
. For this reason, Cottier and Meitinger recommend to adopt
international binding disciplines on export cartels in the framework of the WTO
which “may affect territorial use and allocation of IPRs and work in support of
enhanced market access opportunities”
74)
.
An interesting linkage was drawn between export cartels and antidumping
measures. It was stressed that from a welfare point of view only an international
action directed in the same time at the reform of the antidumping measures and
the abolition of export cartels can be conducive of welfare gains
75)
.
Lastly, in the context of the Japanese example, the point was made that export
cartels were an important mean to implement the Voluntary Export Restraints
(hereafter VERs) and the Multi-Fiber-Agreements. Consequently, the prohibition
and phasing-out of VERs at the WTO level led to the numerical reduction of the
export cartels in Japan
76)
.
d. Export cartels and the revisionary thinking
The debate on export cartels gave rise to a wave of revisionary thinking. Thus,
it was acknowledged that, prior to any further discussion on export cartels, a new
benchmark should be set for the evaluation of the impact that anticompetitive
practices might have on welfare. The old national welfare criterion – which
71)
Paul A. Victor, ‘Export Cartels: An Idea Whose Time Has Passed’ (1992) 60 Antitrust
Law Journal, 573.
72)
Victor (1992), 578.
73)
Thomas Cottier and Ingo Meitinger, ‘T he TRIPs Agreement without a Competition
Agreement?’ (1998) Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Paper No. 65-99, 13, available at
http://www.iew.unibe.ch/unibe/rechtswissenschaft/dwr/iew/content/e3870/e3985/e4122/e4510/ipr
_suppl-lektion_5_ger.pdf (last visited on 17 May 2009).
74)
Ibidem, 14.
75)
Nagaoka (1998), 4.
76)
Ibidem, 10.
17
prohibits cartels in the domestic market, but immunizes them for the exercise of
foreign market power – was suitable for the old “international world”. The new
“globalized world” requires a new global welfare criterion which would prohibit
an anticompetitive practice even if its effects occur only in a foreign market.
An immediate consequence of this ethical re-evaluation of the welfare
criterion should be the establishment of the national treatment in the application of
competition policy. This would mean that domestic and foreign firms as well as
domestic and foreign consumers will be treated in the same way, without
discriminating between them. As an implicit consequence of putting on the same
footing the domestic and the foreign markets, export cartels should be
prohibited
77)
.
Before moving to the next point, one should observe that the constant players
of the trade and competition debate held within the WGTCP were the US, the EU
and Japan. Other Members had occasional inputs, without attempting to be strong
policy-shapers. Per total, 21,08 % of the WTO Members expressed an opinion on
export cartels during the work of the WGTCP. The following table illustrates
which policy-makers except of the constant players mentioned above
presented a policy statement concerning the export cartels. As the table clearly
shows, the occasional players are not many and they mainly represent the
developed world. This could stand whether for the lack of interest of the
developing world in this issue, or for a lack of know-how. Either way, the absence
of a multi-player debate was detrimental to the fate of the trade and competition
debate and led to the elimination of the issue from the WTO agenda.
The work and activity of the WGTCP highlighted one of the contradictions of
the recent trade relations. On the one hand, the issue of export cartels was
discussed for the first time at the multilateral level in an environment were each
Member had a voice and a chance to express a view. On the other hand, the same
WGTCP experience showed that the developing countries need not only a voice
and a forum to express this voice. The developing world needs to be empowered
with know-how. Otherwise their voice risks to play no role at all or even to rebel
against the developed world.
The discussions held within the WGTCP on trade and competition policy
reflect the developments in the Member States legislations. Also, they prove the
shift towards and the preference for market economy. On the other hand, these
discussions highlight the fact that some countries – despite the fact that they have
adopted a competition law – are not ready to play the trade and competition game.
Even if the trade and competition debate was finally expelled from the WTO
ambit, the author of the present paper takes the view that the work of the WGTCP
was highly successful and had a great impact on the competition policies around
the world. First of all, the activity of the WGTCP gave an occasion to the World
77)
Nagaoka (1998), 16.
18
Bank, the UNCTAD and the OECD to submit communications to the WTO.
While doing so, none of the above mentioned IGOs challenged the competence of
the WTO to deal with these issues, thus implicitly accepting that the WTO is the
right forum to address the trade and competition debate.
Also, the trade and competition debate provoked a wave of competition
thinking that reverberated in many of the regional trade organizations and in the
regional trade agreements
78)
. India, for example, considered incorporating
competition clauses in its bilateral trade agreements to prevent global cartels from
entering the country and to punish them for wrongdoing
79)
.
IV. THE POST TRADE AND COMPETITION DEBATE
After the failure of the trade and competition debate within the WTO, three
approaches were adopted in relation to the issue of export cartels: (1) the “no
business no cry” approach, (2) the “business as usual” approach and (3) the
“business reinvented” approach.
1. The “no business no cry” approach
The issue of export cartels was ignored by the WTO after the July package
decision. The reticence of the developing counties and the contradictory positions
of the US and the EU on this subject, led the policy-makers to the conclusion that
it was preferable to close the eyes at the problems raised by export cartels.
The same attitude was adopted by the newly-created International
Competition Network (ICN). The ICN has as mission to identify “subjects of
potential interests to Members” and to “consider proposals for projects including
those aimed at leading to non-binding general guidelines or ‘best practices’
recommendations”
80)
. Also, the ICN Cartel Working Group (CWG) is mandated
“to address the challenges of anti-cartel enforcement, both domestically and
internationally, across the entire range of ICN members and amongst agencies
with differing levels of experience”
81)
. However, the issue of export cartels was
never considered as a subject of potential interest to Members and was never put
on the agenda of the CWG. One plausible explanation of this could be the fact that
the ICN focuses mainly on hard-core cartels. Export cartels, on the other hand, are
78)
UNCTAD, Ways in Which Possible International Agreements on Competition Might Apply
to Developing Countries, TD/B/COM.2/CLP/46/Rev.3, 7 May 2007 .
79)
“Competition Clause May Find a Place in FTAs”, Financial Express, July 5, 2 007.
80)
International Competition Network Op erational Framework, available at
http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/index.php/en/about-icn/op erational-framework
(last visited on 17 May 2009).
81)
International Competition Network Working Grou p on Cartels Mandate, available at
http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/media/archive0611/cartelworkplan2004.pdf (last
visited on 17 May 2009).
19
said to have some pro-competitive effects that outweigh the anti-competitive
damage. Still, the wording of the ICN documents leaves the strong impression that
export cartels represent a “no-issue” in the sense that this question was ignored on
purpose. In the report prepared for the ICN 4
th
Annual Conference the CWG
mentioned that “while the basic understanding of what constitutes a cartel and the
harmful effects of cartels is remarkably consistent across jurisdictions, there are
several complicating issues that give rise to different approaches in defining and
enforcing a cartel prohibition”
82)
. One such complicating issue is the existence of
anti-trust exemptions. Still, this report makes no reference to export cartels neither
as type of collusion with harmful effects, nor as practice exempted from the
application of competition rules. This approach sits very oddly with the fact that
the same competition authorities that argued – within the framework of the WTO
– in favour of a multilateral agreement prohibiting export cartels choose to
disregard this problem within the framework of the ICN.
2. The “business as usual” approach
Other international bodies whose work touches upon the trade and
competition debate did not make any significant inputs into the export cartels
discussion after 2004. For example OECD, in its latest country reviews, showed
that the situation of the export trade exemptions in the US did not change
83)
.
Contrary to the US, Japan undertook a process of revision of its anti-trust
exemptions and, as a result, there were no export cartel exemptions granted in
Japan at the time of the review
84)
.
At the national level, no new initiatives were taken for the abolition of the
export cartel legislation. The FTC and the DoJ in the US and the European
Commission in the EU deal both with competition issues and with trade issues.
Since 2004, none of these bodies undertook any research in relation to export
cartels. Neither have they referred to this issue in any official document.
In the US, the Antitrust Modernization Commission (AMC) was created in
2002 to examine the need “to modernize the antitrust laws”
85)
. One of the aims of
the AMC was to analyze in how far the impunities granted by the export
association legislation to exporters are justified in the 21
st
century
86)
. The most
important findings of the AMC in this sense are the following:
82)
“Building Blocks for Effective Anti-Cartel Regimes (vol. 1) – Defining Hard-Core Cartel
Conduct” (2005), Report prepared by t he ICN Working Group on Cartels, available at
http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/media/library/conference_4th_bonn_2005/Effecti
ve_Anti-Cartel_Regimes_Building_Blocks.pdf (last visited on 17 May 2009 ).
83)
OECD, United States Report on Competition Law and Institutions (2004),
DAF/COMP(2005)13, 14.
84)
OECD, Regulatory Reform – Monitoring Review of Japan, DAFFE/COMP(2004)11/REV1, 20.
85)
Antitrust Modernization Commission Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 1 07-273 § 11053 (1).
86)
AMC Staff, Impunities and Exemptions Discussion Memorandum (11 July 2006), available at:
http://www.amc.gov/pdf/meetings/IE-Statutory%20DiscMemo060711fin.pdf (last visited on 17 May
20
The AMC acknowledged ab initio that any exemption to antitrust laws
benefits only some small and concentrated interest groups, while the costs of the
same exemption are bared by a large number of consumers. Since consumers are
likely to show no opposition to the enactment of exceptions to antitrust laws, the
Congress is likely to hear no complaints from those who bear in fact the cost of
the exemption
87)
.
The AMC recognized that there is no reason that could justify why the
small and medium-sized companies “should be held to a lesser standard of
antitrust compliance than any other companies doing business”
88)
.
The AMC noted that export association legislation raises a ‘particularly
acute concern’ insofar as it may be seen as granting immunity for cartel activity
abroad. For this, “it is inconsistent for US antitrust enforcers to emphasize to
foreign antitrust enforcers the importance of cartel enforcement at the same time
that US law immunizes what some consider to constitute overseas cartel behavior
by American firms”
89)
.
However, in the final recommendations presented to the US Congress and to
the President of the US the AMC made no specific proposal for the repeal of the
export cartel legislation. The AMC only stated in very broad terms that “statutory
immunities from the antitrust laws should be disfavored. They should be granted
rarely, and only where, and for so long as, a clear case has been made that the
conduct in question would subject the actors to antitrust liability and is necessary
to satisfy a specific societal goal that trumps the benefit of a free market to
consumers and the US economy in general”
90)
.
The AMC concluded that the US antitrust laws are “sound” and “sufficiently
flexible to allow for their continued ‘modernization’ as the world continues to
change and our understanding of how markets operate continues to evolve
through decisions by the courts and enforcement agencies”
91)
.
Another authority that adopted the “business as usual” approach was the
Supreme Court of the United States while delivering its decision in the Empagran
case
92)
. Although this case did not raise questions about export cartels, the
approach taken by the Supreme Court in Empagran is relevant to the subject
matter of this paper in so far as the Court clarified the relationship between the
2009); AMC Immunities and Exemptions Study Group, Immunities and Exemptions Working Plan (6
May 2005), available at: http://www.amc.gov/pdf/meetings/ImmunitiesExemptionsStudyPlan.pdf (last
visited on 17 May 2009).
87)
AMC, AMC Report and Recommendations (2007) , p. 335, available at:
http://www.amc.gov/report_recommendation/introduction.pdf (last visited o n 17 May 2009).
88)
Ibidem, p. 352.
89)
AMC Report and Recommendations (2007), 353.
90)
Ibidem, p. 20.
91)
Ibidem, p. 2.
92)
F. Hoffman-La Roche Ltd. v. Empagran, 542 U.S. 155 (2004).
21
existence of a foreign price-fixing activity that has requisite domestic effect and
that has independent foreign effects giving rise to the plaintiff’s claim.
The pre- Empagran case-law attempted an expansive interpretation of
FTAIA, allowing foreign plaintiffs to challenge foreign anticompetitive behavior
under the US antitrust laws. Thus, in Kruman v.Christie's International PLC
93)
, a
Second Circuit decision that involved the two largest auction houses in the world,
the court found that the FTAIA provides a standard for foreign plaintiffs to seek
relief in US courts
94)
. Unlike the majority view on this subject
95)
, the Second
Circuit court established that once the first prong of the FTAIA is met and the
requisite effect on the US commerce is established, the second prong of the
FTAIA – namely, “gives rise to a claim” – did not impose an important barrier to
the establishment of jurisdiction. The interpretation given to FTAIA in the
Kruman decision implies along the lines that if a foreign plaintiff proves that an
US export cartel affects US commerce, the US courts have jurisdiction to judge
the foreign effects in the US.
Taking into account the huge policy implications that the Kruman extensive
interpretation of the FTAIA might have had, the US Supreme Court sought to
clarify this issue in its Empagran case, by holding that:
The FTAIA seeks to make clear to American exporters (and to firms doing
business abroad) that the Sherman Act does not prevent them from entering into
business arrangements (say, joint-selling arrangements), however anticompetitive,
as long as those arrangements adversely affect only foreign markets (underlined by
the author). . . . It does so by removing from the Sherman Act’s reach (1) export
activities and (2) other commercial activities taking place abroad, unless those
activities adversely affect domestic commerce, imports to the United States, or
exporting activities of one engaged in such activities within the United States
96)
.
3. The “business reinvented” approach
If governments seemed to have embraced a “medieval” approach to export
cartels, the academic debate reached a state-of-the-art level concerning the same
topic. New elements were introduced in the debate and new perspectives were
proposed. And one might say, without running the risk of exaggerating, that it is
only due to academia that export cartels are still raised today as an important issue.
While looking for a solution to the export cartel problem, some authors
searched again in the trade and competition arsenal. Such an effort was
accompanied by a philosophical influx and justified by the belief that only by
demystifying the trade and competition debate, a solution could be found to the
more specific issue of export cartels.
93)
284 F. 3d 384 (2d Cir. 2002).
94)
Kruman, 284 F. 3d at 401, 403.
95)
See in this sense Den Norske Stats Oljeselskap As v. Heeremac Vof, 241 F.3d 420 (5
th
Cir. 2001).
96)
542 U.S. 155, 161 (2004) (emphasis in original).
22
In this sense, Gerber emphasized that the future of the WTO is intricately
interwoven with competition law issues. He recognized that “the changes that
would be necessary to introduce and successfully implement competition law in
the WTO are to a large extent the same as those that the institution will need to
make if it is to enrich its role as an institution”
97)
.
Some political science elements were brought into the export cartels debate
and shifted the discussion into new directions. While emphasizing the exodus of
the economics thinking from the trade and competition debate, Kröll illustrated
that “competition policy has been used as a bargaining chip for mutual
concessions in other policy areas like agriculture and services”
98)
.
Interesting results were obtained by a few researchers who applied the
prisoner’s dilemma theory to the export cartels issue. Thus, Hoekman and Saggi
showed that companies originating in a high income country have little incentive to
cartelize in a low income country with a concentrated market structure and a high
tariff. On the other hand, when the low income country has a highly competitive
market, cartelization is highly profitable even if the low income country has a high
tariff. The authors concluded for these reasons that cartelization, combined with a
tariff represent a prisoner’s dilemma in a competitive market structure
99)
.
Sweeney, on the other hand, expressed the view that the incentives to discipline
export cartels present a prisoner’s dilemma in the sense that a country currently
prohibiting export cartels can always make itself better off by allowing them and a
country that currently permits export cartels can make itself worse off by
prohibiting them. Sweeney thus concludes that “in the absence of an agreement, the
world’s trading nations are in equilibrium when they permit export cartels”
100)
.
A similar conclusion was reached by Durand, Galarza, and Mehta who
examined the welfare effects of banning or allowing export cartels. The authors
scrutinized the following situations:
(a) in the situation when both the home and the foreign countries exempt
export cartels from antitrust prosecution, each country gains from its export
industry, but loses from the import sector;
(b) in the situation when the home country and the foreign country ban export
cartels, both countries’ welfare is maximized
101)
. However, this situation is unreal
97)
David J. Gerber, ‘Competition Law and the WTO: Rethinking the Relationship’ (2007) 10
Journal Of International And Economic Law 3, 707.
98)
Daniella Kröll (2007), 170.
99)
Bernard Hoekman and K amal Saggi, ‘Tariff Bindings and Bilateral Cooperation on Export
Cartels’ (2007) 83 Journal Of Development Economics 1, 144-145 .
100)
Brendan Sweeney, ‘Export Cartels: Is There a Need for Global Rules’ ( 2007) 10 Journal
Of International And Economic Law 1, 103- 104.
101)
Benoît Durand, Andrés Font Galarza and Kirtikumar Mehta, ‘The Interface Between
Competition Policy and International Trade Liberalization. Looking into the Future: Applying a
New Virtual Anti-Trust Standard’ (2004) 27 World Competition 1, 7 .
23
– noticed the authors – due to the fact that the home country and the foreign
country have a strong incentive to exempt export cartels.
Thus, when both the home and the foreign country ban export cartels, each
country reaches a welfare level of 15. However, if the home country chooses to
allow export cartels while the foreign country still bans this practice, the welfare
of the home country rises from 15 to 20 while the foreign country welfare falls
from 15 to 6. For this, the authors conclude that “if countries could co-ordinate
their antitrust policy to prosecute export cartels they would all reach a higher
welfare level”
102)
.
Other important inputs concerning the alleged beneficial or detrimental effects
of the export cartel legislation were made by Bhattacharjea who criticized the lack
of theoretical or empirical foundations of this debate and noticed that, in contrast
to the works published in the field of international cartels, no serious “arguments
seem to have been entered at any stage of the (export cartels) debate”
103)
.
In a 2006 study on the effects of the ETCs on exports, Levenstein and Suslow
concluded that nothing in their analysis “lends support to the notion that ETCs
increase exports above what they would be absent an antitrust exemption”
104)
.
This confirms the results of earlier studies on the ETC and WPA that economic
impact of these exemptions was small both in assisting US industries and in
promoting the exercise of market power by US firms.
Becker highlighted that, even in the advocates’ team, few would overtly agree
that an export cartel is something more than an attempt to enhance the exporting
state’s welfare at the expense of the target state or of the global welfare
105)
. Becker
also noted that “export cartel exemptions lead into a downwards spiral of
anticompetitive measures and counter-measures taken by governments and market
participants”
106)
.
4. The solutions
A remarkable feature of the post trade and competition debate on export
cartels is the endeavor to “produce” a solution to this debate.
More and more researchers seem to agree that a global consumer welfare
criterion should be at the basis of any effort to solve the export cartel issue.
Whatever path the policy-makers will choose to fall back on, the ideal that global
markets require global answers should prevail.
102)
Ibidem, at 8.
103)
Aditya Bhattacharjea, ‘Export Cartels – A Developin g Country Perspective’ (2004) 38
Journal Of World Trade 2, 336.
104)
Margaret C. Levenstein and Va lerie Y. Suslow, ‘The Economic Impact of the U.S. Expor t
trading Company Act’ (2006) Ross School of Business Working Pap er No. 1036, 25.
105)
Florian Becker, ‘The Case of Export Cartel Exemptions: Between Competition and
Protectionism’ (2007) 3 Journal Of Competition Law And Economics 1, 115 .
106)
Ibidem, at 118.
24
Another matter of principle that should receive attention at an early stage of
the decision-making process is the developing states exemption. Some authors
agree that an exemption for developing states is justified and should cover only
cases of export from developing into developed states
107)
.
Lastly, it is important to consider what Levenstein and Suslow call the
“unintended consequence” of a global ban on export cartels. According to these
authors, practice shows that the elimination of cooperation as a legal possibility
can lead to a higher merger activity or to the lessening of competition in the
domestic market
108)
. This finding is in line with the ideas of the cartel literature
that confirmed that prohibiting cartels speeds concentration
109)
.
Turning to the feasible solutions now, the survey of the academic literature on
this subject leads to the identification of two paths of action for dealing with
export cartels: unilateral or non-cooperative action and cooperative action. The
following chart illustrates this classification.
Non-Cooperative/Unilateral Action on Export Cartels
A State that fights the incoming effects of an export cartel within its
jurisdiction can act unilaterally – that is, take action based on its sole will. A State
might take unilateral action based on hard-law measures or unilateral action based
on soft-law measures.
(a) Some trade and competition scholars argue that, due to the difficulties that
underpin all the proposed solutions to the export cartel issue, it might be
reasonable to focus academic and political attention on competition advocacy and
promotion of transparency in decision-making as a solution to this issue
110)
. This
accounts for unilateral action based on soft-law measures.
(b) There are however other authors who promote unilateral action based on
hard law measures, in the sense that a compulsory act is required from the
decision-makers. One unilateral response that could be given by the importing
state in case of a foreign export cartel acting within its jurisdiction is to allow its
own exporters to collude. Reciprocity however could be the start line of lose-lose
race in the global market. As highlighted before, when two countries ban export
cartels, their welfare level is 15; when two countries allow export cartels their
welfare level falls to 10. Furthermore, Hoekman and Holmes explained in an
107)
Sweeney (2007), 111-113.
108)
Margaret C. Levenstein, Valerie Y. Suslow, ‘The Changing International Stat us of Export
Cartel Exemptions’ (2006) 20 American University International Law Revie w, 813-814.
109)
Tony Freyer, Regulating Big Business: Antitrust in Great Britain and Ame rica 1880-1990
(1992) Cambridge University Press, Cambridge; Geor ge Symeonidis, The Effects of Competition :
Cartel Policy and the Evolution of Strategy and Structure in British I ndustry (2002) The MIT
Press: Cambridge.
110)
Sweeney (2007), 111.
25
earlier paper that, even under conditions of reciprocity, some states will continue
to ripe more benefits from their export cartels than other states
111)
.
The importing state may pursue another unilateral path and apply its own
competition law extraterritorially. Extraterritoriality, however, is escorted by a set
of intricacies that transform this option into a very complicated procedural matter.
Gaining access to information about the foreign exporters, fighting exporters’
immunity under the act of state doctrine or based on foreign sovereign compulsion
or international comity
112)
and enforcing a judgment against firms that do not hold
any assets in the importing state – these are only a few of the complicating issues
that render extraterritoriality a very difficult option
113)
.
Lastly, a state could unilaterally and – most probable – in breach with the
WTO agreements suspend some of the GATT/WTO rights (market access,
protection for intellectual property goods). This option is the one that would pose
the highest threat to the whole WTO system.
Cooperative Action on Export Cartels
The cooperative action on export cartels is the action based on the will of two
or more states. Depending on the number of the wills involved, the cooperative
action can be bilateral, regional, plurilateral or multilateral
114)
.
The Bilateral Action
Ryan argues that “bilateral action would require the signing of bilateral co-
operation agreements between jurisdictions which would oblige one party to
respond positively to a request for investigatory support from the other party, even
in cases where the practice under investigation is not a violation of the
competition law of the requested party”
115)
. Ryan furthermore concludes that
regional groupings of competition jurisdiction and enforcement agencies represent
the least problematic of the various approaches to export cartels
116)
.
Sweeney, on the other hand, concluded that the gain form bilateral agreements
would be minimal due to the fact that they focus on hardcore cartels and lack
dispute settlement mechanisms
117)
.
111)
Bernard Hoekman and Peter Holmes, ‘Competition Po licy, Developing Countries and the
WTO’ (1999) World Bank Working Paper No. 2211, 19.
112)
Ulrich I mmenga, ‘Export Cartels and Voluntary Export Restraints between Trade and
Competition Policy’ (1995) 4 Pacific Rim Law And Policy Journal 93, 125-126.
113)
Sweeney (2007), 102-103.
114)
Mitsuo Matsushita, Thomas J. Schoenbaum, P etros C. Mavroidis, The World Trade
Organization: Law, Practice and Policy (2006), Oxford: Oxford University P ress, 886.
115)
Stephen Ryan, ‘The Treatment of Export Cartels in EU and US Law’( forthcoming), 10.
116)
Ibidem, 11.
117)
Sweeney (2007), 104.
26
The Multilateral Action
Two main ingredients are conceivable as parts of a multilateral action against
export cartels: (a) multilateral agreement on export cartels and (b) competition
authority with investigatory powers. The following combinations are possible:
only agreement, agreement and supranational oversight or only supranational
oversight.
It is true that mandatory dispute resolution is impossible if countries cannot
agree on the rule that will govern the dispute. However, “because a
comprehensive code is not feasible today, it does not follow that efforts looking
toward future convergence are futile”
118)
.
Academia identified various types of potential export cartel agreements.
Guzman proposed to apply national treatment principles to export cartels
119)
. This
would lead to an agreement “to treat incoming and outgoing anticompetitive
conduct alike”
120)
.
Sweeney noted that, since “the most appropriate judge of the anti-competitive
nature of an export cartel is in fact the importing state”
121)
, a feasible solution
would be to conclude an agreement giving jurisdiction to the importing state. The
opposite solution can be a valid bargain as well, namely, an agreement in which
exporting state considers foreign harm
122)
.
Bhattacharjea suggested a multilateral agreement along the lines of a
“reverse” anti-dumping agreement. Where the export prices would exceed some
“normal value” – that is, the reverse of normal dumping – the importing state
would be entitled to impose a sanction on the colluding foreign firms
123)
. The
same author pleads for an agreement that allows the suspension of TRIPs and
other GATT/WTO rights as a penalty for anti-competitive behavior by foreign
exporters
124)
. Bhattacharjea’s proposals provoked a storm of reactions in the
academic world. While Sweeney agrees that an import duty is an approach that
makes a lot of theoretical sense, he argues that in practice such a duty will not
compensate for consumer losses and that “only in very limited circumstances will
a tariff applied to the cartel members induce the cartel members to disband the
cartel”
125)
. On the other side of the opinion spectrum, Magnus argued that “global
antitrust discussions can much more usefully focus on what importing countries
118)
Robert Pitofsky, ‘Competition P olicy in a Global Economy – Today and Tomorrow’
(1998), available at www.ftc.gov/speeches/pitofsky/global.shtm (last visited o n 17 May 2009).
119)
Andre w Guz man, ‘The Case for In ternational Antitrust’ (2004) 22 Berkeley Journal Of
International Law 355, 372.
120)
Becker (2007), 126.
121)
Sweeney (2007), 106.
122)
Bernard Hoekman and Petros C. Mavroid is, ‘Economic Development, Competition Po licy
and the World Trade Organization’ (2003) 37 (1) Journal Of World Trad e 1, 20.
123)
Bhattacharjea (2004), 353.
124)
Bhattacharjea (2004), 356.
125)
Sweeney (2007), 102-103.
27
do (under their antitrust laws) to limit imports, rather than on what exporting
countries do not do (under their antitrust laws) to limit joint exports”
126)
.
The nature and the political issues underlying the export cartels suggest that
supranational oversight by an international tribunal is desirable. The WTO is
recognized by many scholars as the most suitable candidate for this position due
to its half a century expertise in trade
127)
. However, many unsolved problems pave
the way to recognizing the WTO as a supranational competition authority.
Summing up the results of the post trade and competition momentum, one
should notice that there are fewer states nowadays that grant explicit exemption
for export cartels. However, Levenstein and Suslow concluded that “the legal
status of export cartels is now more, not less, ambiguous”
128)
due to the fact that
enforcement became conditional on domestic harm and due to the lack of
conclusive information. For this, Levenstein, Suslow and other scholars
recognized that despite the already published studies and papers on export cartels,
more antitrust and economics literature is needed on this subject. Furthermore,
more comparative studies are needed about cartels’ relationship to politics,
political culture and law
129)
.
A wave of thinking in the trade and competition debate recognized that
confidence-building is as important as solution-finding. Like Durand, Galarza and
Mehta put it, any measure that would bring about the necessary paradigm shift in
the trade and competition debate “could arise only out of the conviction that this
will work in favour of everybody’s ultimate interest”
130)
.
The interdependence between global trade and global peace was brought into
light again.
Finally, a key question raised today concerns the solution that should be
adopted in relation to the export cartel issue. One should note first of all that none
of the solutions proposed until now by the academia is “trouble-free”. While some
suggestions collide with serious political weaknesses, others are powerless from a
legal reasoning point of view. I propose following a policy level analysis and
choosing the solution which the best from the point of view of its costs.
A thorough analysis of the proposed solutions shows that the non-
cooperative/unilateral action implies that on a first policy level export cartel
legislation should remain in place and only on a second policy level action should
be taken. Such a policy structure is quite dangerous not only because it creates
double costs (due to the double policy level in place), but also because the measures
126)
John R. Magnus, ‘Joint Export Trade Provisions in Antitrust Laws: A Supporter’s
Perspective’ (2005) 39 Journal Of World Trade 1, 184.
127)
Eleanor M. Fox, ‘International Antitrust and the Doha Dome’ (200 3) 43 Virginia Journal
Of International Law 911, 926-27.
128)
Levenstein, Suslow (2005), 812.
129)
Fear (2006), 26.
130)
Durand, Galarza and Mehta (2004), 4.
28
based on unilateral action can provoke unwanted reactions from other trading
partners and can lead to conflicts. This can be observed in relation to some
countries’ attempt to apply their antitrust law extraterritorially. Last but not least,
unilateral action on export cartels is very likely to sabotage the multilateral trading
system by suspending TRIPs, GATT or other WTO rights. For this reason, the great
majority of scholars writing on export cartels support a cooperative approach for
solving this problem. The author of this paper endorses the same approach.
The cooperative action, on the other hand, can take two forms:
(a) cooperative action with one policy level and (b) cooperative action with
two policy levels.
Cooperative action on export cartels in the form of a multilateral agreement
will require expenses only for the negotiation of the agreement. On the other
hand, cooperative action on export cartels in the form of multilateral agreement
plus supranational oversight will require costs not only for the negotiation of the
agreement, but also for the creation and functioning of the supranational
oversight. A preliminary conclusion then would be that cooperative action with
one policy level is cheaper and therefore preferable to cooperative action with two
policy levels.
However, I argue that one should consider other factors except the costs. First
of all, no agreement is “violation-free”; no matter who gave the promise to honor
a deal, there would be always an incentive for breaching the export cartel
agreement. Second, a breach of a multilateral agreement can easily lead to the
breakdown of the whole multilateral trading system. That is why the effort to
conceive a solution for export cartels in the form of an agreement should be
accompanied by a parallel effort to prevent and punish breaches. In case of not
considering this aspect, the price of having in place a multilateral agreement
without oversight can be higher than having the oversight in the first instance.
Lastly, when considering the supranational oversight as a compulsory element
of the solution for export cartels, it is commendable to balance the financial costs
with other benefits that might arise from having in place supranational oversight
for the export cartel agreement. I presume that the WTO is the most suitable
authority to be entrusted with the supervision of the export cartel agreement
131)
.
Therefore, the author of the present paper believes that the costs of having a WTO
body responsible for export cartel issues will be compensated by the following
benefits:
The WTO supranational oversight of export cartel issues will bring a new
wisdom into the WTO. The recent Telmex case, many of the Anti-Dumping
131)
The author of this paper is of course aware of all the theoretical and practical difficulties
that accompany such a prop osition. However, the results of her research could not identify another
institution that could serve as an en forcement mechanis m better than the WTO. That is why she
presumes and recommends that once a multilateral agreement on export cartels will be concluded ,
the WTO should serve as the accompanying enforcement element of the agree ment.
29
Agreement issues and the TRIPs experience show there is need for competition
law thinking in the WTO. A specialized committee on export cartels can develop
into a competition law committee or restart the activity of the WGTCP. Thus,
from a specialized body the committee on export cartels can grow into a
multilateral antitrust agency or into a consultative body on antitrust issues. Either
way, such a body would definitely benefit both trade and competition and would
bring more legitimacy to some of the WTO actions.
A WTO export cartel body would also contribute to the confidence
building between the WTO members. Trade and competition was excluded from
the Doha negotiations due to the low level of confidence that existed between
Members. Antitrust was perceived as a secret gun that the developed world tried
to use against the developing world. Once the WTO members could agree on any
of the trade and competition issues raised during the Doha negotiations – and here
the export cartels could be a prime problem to agree on – the level of confidence
in the WTO and in the trading partners will increase.
Having a WTO export cartel body will also prevent breaching the
agreement. This in turn will enhance the aura of fairness which is essential for the
well-being of the multilateral trading system.
CONCLUSION
This paper pursued the development of the academic and political writings on
export cartels from the adoption of the Webb-Pomerene Act until today. Four
phases of the export cartel debate were identified and analyzed. The following
conclusions can be drawn to bring to a close this paper:
Despite almost one hundred years of debate, there is still little known about the
export cartels, about how they work and about their incoming or outgoing effects.
The export cartels debate has not changed a great deal in the last one hundred
years: the same dichotomist approach is applied and an export cartel is always
seen against the “good or bad” background.
The government ordered research on export cartels is almost absent. The
export cartel debate is ongoing only due to the academia. It is also due to scholars
that economic, political and philosophical thinking was introduced into the export
cartel debate.
Even if neither the export cartels debate, nor the WTO trade and competition
debate have delivered “enforceable” results so far, both debates prove to be
successful. First of all, these debates represented a necessary process of learning.
Second, the trade and competition debate within the WTO provoked a period of
renaissance for the competition culture around the world. This momentum
delivered competition law talks within the regional trade organizations and
competition law provisions being negotiated into more free trade agreements. The
same momentum created the required conditions for the adoption of competition
laws around the world.
30
References
Andrew, R. Dick. (1996). Identifying Contracts, Combinations and
Conspiracies in Restraint of Trade, 17 Managerial And Decision Economics 2,
213 Becker, Florian. (2007). The Case of Export Cartel Exemptions: Between
Competition and Protectionism, 3 Journal Of Competition Law And Economics 1,
115 Bhattacharjea, Aditya. (2004). Export Cartels A Developing Country
Perspective, 38 Journal Of World Trade 2, 336
Diamond, Sidney A. (1944). The Webb-Pomerene Act and Export Trade
Associations, 44 Columbia Law Review 6, 832
Dick, Andrew R. (1992). Are Export Cartels Efficiency-Enhancing or Monopoly-
Promoting? Evidence from the Webb-Pomerene Experience, 15 Research In Law
And Economics, 89-127
Dick, Andrew R. (1996). When Are Cartels Stable Contracts?, 39 Journal Of
Law And Economics 1, 255-257
Diebold, G. (1952). The End of the ITO: Essays in International Finance No.
16, Princeton: Princeton University, para. 2.5
Drache, Daniel. (2000). The Short but Significant Life of the International
Trade Organization: Lessons for Our Time, CSGR Working Paper No. 62/00, 28
Dür, Andreas. (2007). Foreign Discrimination, Protection for Exporters, and
U.S. Trade Liberalization, International Studies Quaterly 51, 457-480
Durand, Benoît & Galarza, Andrés Font & Mehta, Kirtikumar. (2004). The
Interface Between Competition Policy and International Trade Liberalization.
Looking into the Future: Applying a New Virtual Anti-Trust Standard, 27 World
Competition 1, 7
Edwards, Corwin D. (1944). International Cartels as Obstacles to
International Trade, 34 The American Economic Review 1, 331-333
Evenett, Simon J. & Levenstein, Margaret C. & Suslow, Valerie Y. (2002).
International Cartel Enforcement: Lessons from the 1990s, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper No. 2680, 1233, available at
http://ssrn.com/abstract=265741 (last visited on 17 May 2009)
Feinstein, Charles H. & Temin, Peter & Tonniolo, Gianni. (1997). The Legacy
of the First War, in The European Economy between the Wars Oxford: OUP, 18-
37 Fournier, Leslie T. (1932). The Purpose and Results of the Webb-Pomerene
Law, 22 The American Economic Review 1, 20
Fox, Eleanor M. (2003). International Antitrust and the Doha Dome, 43
Virginia Journal Of International Law 911, 926-27
Freyer, Tony. (1992). Regulating Big Business: Antitrust in Great Britain and
31
America 1880-1990, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge;
Gerber, David J. (2007). Competition Law and the WTO: Rethinking the
Relationship, 10 Journal Of International And Economic Law 3, 707
Guzman, Andrew. (2004). The Case for International Antitrust, 22 Berkeley
Journal Of International Law 355, 372
Hoekman, Bernard & Holmes, Peter. (1999). Competition Policy, Developing
Countries and the WTO, World Bank Working Paper No. 2211, 19
Hoekman, Bernard & Mavroidis, Petros C. (2003). Economic Development,
Competition Policy and the World Trade Organization, 37 (1) Journal Of World
Trade 1, 20
Hoekman, Bernard & Saggi, Kamal. (2007). Tariff Bindings and Bilateral
Cooperation on Export Cartels, 83 Journal Of Development Economics 1, 144-
145 Immenga, Ulrich. (1995). Export Cartels and Voluntary Export Restraints
between Trade and Competition Policy, 4 Pacific Rim Law And Policy Journal
93, 125-126
Jones, Eliot. (1920). The Webb-Pomerene Act, 28 The Journal Of Political
Economy 9, 754
Judt, Tony. (2005). Postwar: A History of Europe since 1945, New York:
Penguin Books, 107
Kirsh, Benjamin S. (1928). Foreign Trade Functions of Trade Associations:
The Legal Aspects, 76 University Of Pennsilvania Law Review 8, 894
Knorr, Klaus E. (1946). The Problem of International Cartels and
Intergovernmental Commodity Agreements, 55 The Yale Law Journal 5, 1105
Koch, F. E. (1945). Cartels as Instruments of International Economic
Organization. Public and Private Legal Aspects of International Cartels, 8 The
Modern Law Review 3, 131
Kreps. Theodore J. (1945), Cartels, a Phase of Business Haute Politique, 35
The American Economic Review 2, 309
Kronstein, Heinrich & Leighton, Gertrude. (1946). Cartel Control: A record
of Failure, 55 The Yale Law Journal 2, 297
Larson, David A. (1970), An Economic Analysis of the Webb-Pomerene Act,
13 Journal Of Law And Economics, 461-500
Levenstein, Margaret C. & Suslow, Valerie Y. (2006). The Changing
International Status of Export Cartel Exemptions, 20 American University
International Law Review, 813-814
Levenstein, Margaret C. & Suslow, Valerie Y. (2006). The Economic Impact
of the U.S. Export trading Company Act, Ross School of Business Working Paper
No. 1036, 25
Magnus, John R. (2005). Joint Export Trade Provisions in Antitrust Laws: A
Supporter’s Perspective, 39 Journal Of World Trade 1, 184
Marsden, Philip. (2003). A Competition Policy for the WTO, Cameron May,
32
London, 59
Matsushita, Mitsuo & Schoenbaum, Thomas J. & Mavroidis, Petros C.
(2006). The World Trade Organization: Law, Practice and Policy, Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 886
Moon, Bruce E. (2000). Dilemmas of International Trade, Oxford: Westwood
Press, 91
Nagaoka, Sadao. (1998). International Trade Aspects of Competition Policy,
NBER Working Paper 6720, 3 available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w6720.pdf
(last visited on 17 May 2009)
Notz, William. (1919). Cartels During the War, 27 The Journal Of Political
Economy 1, 6-7
Notz, William. (1920). International Private Agreements in the Form of
Cartels, Syndicates, and Other Combinations, 28 The Journal Of Political
Economy 8, 667-671
Notz, William. (1929). Ten Years’ Operation of the Webb Law, 19 The
American Economic Review 1, 19
Robert Pitofsky. (1998). Competition Policy in a Global Economy Today
and Tomorrow, available at www.ftc.gov/speeches/pitofsky/global.shtm (last
visited on 17 May 2009)
Schultz, Christian. (2002). Export Cartels and Domestic Markets, 2 Journal
Of Industry, Competition And Trade 3, 223-246
Snow, Chauncey D. (1924). American Foreign Trade Problems, 14 The
American Economic Review 1, 7
Sweeney, Brendan. (2007). Export Cartels: Is There a Need for Global Rules,
10 Journal Of International And Economic Law 1, 103- 104
Symeonidis, George. (2002). The Effects of Competition: Cartel Policy and
the Evolution of Strategy and Structure in British Industry, The MIT Press:
Cambridge
Victor, Paul A. (1992). Export Cartels: An Idea Whose Time Has Passed, 60
Antitrust Law Journal, 573
Waller, Spencer Weber. (1992). The Failure of the Export Trading Company
Program, 17 North Carolina Journal Of International Law And Commercial
Regulation, 251-252
Watson, Peter S. & Flynn, Joseph E. & Conwell, Chad C. (1999). Completing
the World Tradeing System:Proposals for a Millennium Round, The Hague:
Kluwer Law International, 349
Webb, Steven B. (1980). Tariffs, Cartels, Technology and Growth in the
German Steel Industry, 1879 to 1914, 40 The Journal Of Economic History 2, 309-
330

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT